Government-Household_analogy

Government-Household analogy

Government-Household analogy

Rhetorical analogy


The Government-Household analogy refers to rhetoric in political economic discourse that compares the finances of a federal government to those of a household. The analogy has frequently been made in debates about government debt, with critics of government debt arguing that greater government debt is equivalent to a household taking on more debt.[1][2]

The analogy has been characterized by economists as misleading and false, as the functions and constraints of governments and households are vastly dissimilar.[3][4][5][6] Differences include that governments can print money,[7][8][9] interest rates on government borrowing may be cheaper than individual borrowing,[7][8] governments can increase their budgets through taxation,[7][8] governments have indefinite planning horizons,[10] national debt may be held primarily domestically (the equivalent of household members owing each other),[10] governments typically have greater collateral for borrowing,[11] and contractions in government spending can cause or prolong economic crises and increase the debt of the government.[6] For governments, the main risks of overspending may revolve around inflation rather than the size of the debt per se.[9][10]

According to economist and Nobel laureate William Vickrey,[3]

This fallacy seems to stem from a false analogy to borrowing by individuals. Current reality is almost the exact opposite. Deficits add to the net disposable income of individuals, to the extent that government disbursements that constitute income to recipients exceed that abstracted from disposable income in taxes, fees, and other charges. This added purchasing power, when spent, provides markets for private production, inducing producers to invest in additional plant capacity, which will form part of the real heritage left to the future. This is in addition to whatever public investment takes place in infrastructure, education, research, and the like. Larger deficits, sufficient to recycle savings out of a growing gross domestic product (GDP) in excess of what can be recycled by profit-seeking private investment, are not an economic sin but an economic necessity. Deficits in excess of a gap growing as a result of the maximum feasible growth in real output might indeed cause problems, but we are nowhere near that level. Even the analogy itself is faulty. If General Motors, AT&T, and individual households had been required to balance their budgets in the manner being applied to the Federal government, there would be no corporate bonds, no mortgages, no bank loans, and many fewer automobiles, telephones, and houses.


References

  1. Barnes, Lucy; Hicks, Timothy (2021). "Are Policy Analogies Persuasive? The Household Budget Analogy and Public Support for Austerity". British Journal of Political Science. 52 (3): 1296–1314. doi:10.1017/S0007123421000119. ISSN 0007-1234. S2CID 236257379.
  2. Editor, Philip Aldrick, Economics. "BBC 'misled viewers' on scale of national debt". The Times. ISSN 0140-0460. Retrieved 2021-07-19. {{cite news}}: |last= has generic name (help)CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  3. Krugman, Paul (2015). "The austerity delusion". The Guardian. Retrieved 2021-07-19.
  4. Wren-Lewis, Simon (2015-02-19). "The Austerity Con". London Review of Books. Vol. 37, no. 4. ISSN 0260-9592. Retrieved 2021-07-19.
  5. "Why the federal budget can't be managed like a household budget". The Guardian. 2013-03-26. Retrieved 2021-07-19.
  6. Smith, Warwick. "Why the federal budget is not like a household budget". The Conversation. Retrieved 2021-07-19.
  7. "Does the National Debt Matter?| St. Louis Fed". www.stlouisfed.org. Retrieved 2021-07-19.
  8. Gordon, Roger H.; Varian, Hal R. (1988). "Intergenerational risk sharing". Journal of Public Economics. 37 (2): 185–202. doi:10.1016/0047-2727(88)90070-9. hdl:2027.42/27078. S2CID 52202708.



Share this article:

This article uses material from the Wikipedia article Government-Household_analogy, and is written by contributors. Text is available under a CC BY-SA 4.0 International License; additional terms may apply. Images, videos and audio are available under their respective licenses.